R7

"Ain't Gonna Study War No More"

My Photo
Name:
Location: Brooklyn, New York, United States

Right-To-Life Party, Christian, Anti-War, Pro-Life, Bible Fundamentalist, Egalitarian, Libertarian Left

Monday, September 06, 2004

Government Interventionism in Ireland, Part 1



Ireland at the turn of the 20th century was poised for change. Most of Ireland’s inhabitants wanted to alter in some respect the nature of their relationship with Great Britain, which had been interfering in Irish affairs for more than 700 years. In 1801 the British government had even declared Ireland to be, constitutionally, a province of the United Kingdom, ruling the island directly from London. This sat well with the pro-British minority in the north.

By the end of the 19th century, however, the majority of the Irish, the Catholics, were no longer willing to be passive political minions of the British Empire. This had been demonstrated on no fewer than four occasions through attempts at organized rebellion over a period of less than 70 years. These were the United Irishman’s uprising in 1798, Robert Emmet’s rebellion in 1803, the 1848 rebellion of the Young Irelanders, and the Fenian Uprising of 1867.

All four insurrections failed in their intended goal — the political separation of Ireland from Great Britain — but they demonstrated a persistent willingness on the part of the Irish to resort to violence for political purposes, and, just as important, they were proof that the status quo would never be allowed to stand for long before further blood was shed over the question of who would control the political fate of the Irish people.

Since the 1880s, Liberal governments had been introducing “home rule” legislation in the House of Commons in hopes of placating separatist sentiments in Ireland. In fact, the only measurable effect of their efforts was to further polarize relations between Ireland’s Catholic majority, which wanted some degree of self-government but disagreed widely on the form, and the unionists, the pro-British Protestant minority concentrated mostly in the urban centers of Ulster. This polarization was largely unnecessary. Home rule, as foreseen by both the Liberals and the Irish Parliamentary Party (IPP), the only significant nationalist party, would have created nothing more than a glorified local government to run Ireland at the behest of the British crown.

Still, it was more than the unionists were prepared to accept, and the question of home rule soon became a political non-issue. The Liberal Party was wary of going head to head with empire-minded voters in England or radical Protestants in northeast Ireland.

Much as the Liberals may have wanted, the issue would nonetheless not go away. This was particularly clear after a pair of general elections in 1910 left the Liberals with a mere plurality of seats at Westminster, requiring that a coalition government be formed with the IPP’s 80 or so MPs to fashion a working majority in the House of Commons. The IPP was not going to enter a coalition without a promise of home rule. Caving in to more immediate political realities, the Liberal government finally set home rule to commence in 1914.

The effect of passing the Home Rule Act was to push Ireland to the brink of civil war. In January 1913 the Ulster Unionist Council set up the Ulster Volunteer Force, a private militia, to resist any attempts to make Ireland more Irish (or less British). In response, the Irish National Volunteers were formed in November to defend home rule. Brian Feeney, in his recent book Sinn Fein: A Hundred Turbulent Years, writes, “By summer 1914 both sets of Volunteers, north and south, had acquired weapons.” The British government was now in the uncomfortable position of having to mend fences between armed camps.

The trouble was that by 1914 the Protestant and Catholic peoples of Ireland were so completely at odds with one another that there was virtually no possibility of peacefully satisfying their common aspirations.

The question of governing Ireland had become a zero-sum game. Catholics were looking for any gesture from the British that signaled respect for their goal of greater autonomy from London. Protestants, on the other hand, were miles away from tolerating even the slightest compromise on Ireland’s political future. No matter that home rule was an innocuous measure, at worst; the unionists were not going to accept it, in any form, without violence.


Objections to home rule

What was it about home rule, a minimalist concession to the wishes of the overwhelming majority of Ireland’s population, that drove Protestants to defy their government and contemplate plunging their country into internecine warfare to stop it?

Quite simply, home rule was viewed as the “thin end of the wedge,” a slippery slope that unionists feared could lead only to an Irish government. If home rule was nothing more than a token symbolic act to satisfy Catholics, it equally symbolized for the Protestant a step down the road towards Dublin rule.

Explanation of such obstinacy typically is presented in terms of Protestants’ fear of losing a centuries-old dominant position in Irish society, blind political loyalty to the British crown, and deeply felt religious bigotry. These factors admittedly should not be lightly discounted in understanding the conflict in Ireland.

Overlooked in such discussions, equally if not more important to understanding the motivations of the unionist culture, is the fact that the face of Irish separatism in 1914 was one of protectionism, socialism, theocratic decree, and cultural dominance. Those who comment on the history of Ireland’s civil unrest underrate the impact that face must have had on Protestant thinking.

Under a Dublin government, Protestants feared, free commerce would be stifled in a sea of authoritarian controls, government education policy would support Irish over British culture and the development and promotion of the Irish over the English language, and Catholicism over Protestantism — strong incentives for every class of Ulsterman to oppose even the slightest concession to nationalist desires.

Looking beyond the veneer of separatist views on the union, Protestants would have known that nationalist leaders ultimately wanted to create an Irish government powerful enough to control just about every major facet of public life, none of which would have worked out to the Protestants’ benefit.

Protestants may have been overly worried about the possibility of total Irish independence, but they were under no illusions about the outcome if such ever came to pass. Evidence of their considerable fear is seen in a commentary written by Ulster MP James Craig, in the Morning Post newspaper, in January 1911:

Neither Mr. Redmond [leader of the IPP] nor the English people has any conception of the deep- rooted determination of the sturdy men and women of Ulster [to resist] the encroachment on their civil and religious liberties that would naturally follow the establishment of a parliament in Dublin. [Emphasis added.]
A year earlier, unionist Walter Long gave a speech before the Ulster Unionist Council proclaiming that “home rule for Ireland would mean the loss of individual liberty, the absolute insecurity of property, and the negation of everything [unionists] cared for affecting the welfare of the country.” [Emphasis added.]


Nationalism and laissez faire

The timing of these developments should be evaluated in full context. In 1914, Britain, like the United States and other industrialized countries, was experiencing the tremendous material benefits of a century of laissez-faire economic policies. In Ireland, the most visible advantages of 19th-century capitalism could be seen in Ulster, where industries thrived and living standards soared, relative to the rest of the country. The Protestant businessmen of Ulster knew, from a century of evidence, that free trade and limited government were the keys to wealth and prosperity. Such men would have been strongly suspicious of government interference.

By contrast, the economic objectives of the nationalists were interventionist on the one end and totally socialist on the other. There was no room for the free market in the nationalist philosophy. If Protestants found the IPP’s hopes for an assembly with what Feeney calls “paltry powers” a worrisome prospect, then the fully articulated economic policies of prominent nationalist spokesmen must have been absolutely horrifying.

For example, Arthur Griffith, who founded an organization called Sinn Fein (“ourselves alone”) in 1905, wanted economic independence from Britain, preferably under a system of dual monarchy, and adopted the strongly nationalistic and protectionist views of German economist Friedrich List (1789–1846) accordingly. At Sinn Fein’s inaugural meeting, Griffith praised List for “brushing aside the fallacies of Adam Smith and his tribe, [and pointing] out that between the individual and humanity stands, and must continue to stand, a great fact — the nation.”

Griffith wanted an isolationist Ireland that would “maintain self-existence and independence by its own power and resources” alone. In his view, Irish industries would develop and thrive only if free trade was curtailed. He paid lip service to capitalism, stating that “ ;Capital and Labour … are essential and complementary to each other” rather than antagonistic, but with the proviso that “it is the duty of the organized nation to protect Labour, and to secure for it the profits of production, not a mere competitive wage.” Flowery tributes to the partnership of “Capital and Labour” aside, the redistributionist intention here is obvious.

Sounding the rallying cry for collectivism, Griffith called on the Irish people to “place our duty to our country before our personal interests, and live not each for himself but each for all.” Griffith longed for an Irish government that would boycott English goods, raise protective tariffs, subsidize agriculture, embark on massive public-works projects, raise an Irish merchant fleet, and institute a “Buy Irish” campaign. His Sinn Fein philosophy was very popular in intellectual circles.

At the “other end” of this economic spectrum was James Connolly, a popular and very radical nationalist and labor agitator who actually preferred another armed insurrection over politics to mold a new, socialist Ireland. (He would be executed for his part in the 1916 Easter Uprising.) Connolly formed the Irish Socialist Republican Party in 1896 and later, in 1910, worked for the Socialist Party of Ireland. He was the Belfast organizer, later acting secretary general, of the General Workers Union (which would paralyze Dublin in a general strike in 1913), and, in 1914, commandant of the Irish Citizen Army, another private militia.

In “Socialism and Nationalism” (1897), published in the Irish magazine Shan Van Vocht, Connolly declared that “if the national movement of our day is not merely to re- enact the old sad tragedies of our past history, it must show itself capable of rising to the exigencies of the moment.”

If you remove the English army tomorrow and hoist the green flag over Dublin Castle, unless you set about the organisation of the Socialist Republic your efforts would be in vain. England would still rule you. She would rule you through her capitalists, through her landlords, through her financiers, through the whole array of commercial and individualist institutions she has planted in this country.… England would still rule you to your ruin, even while your lips offered hypocritical homage at the shrine of that Freedom whose cause you had betrayed. Nationalism without Socialism — without a reorganisation of society on the basis of a broader and more developed form of … common property…. — is only national recreancy. It would be tantamount to a public declaration that our oppressors had so far succeeded in inoculating us with their perverted conceptions of justice and morality that we had finally decided to accept those conceptions as our own, and no longer needed an alien army to force them upon us. [Emphasis added.]
As Feeney points out, “Belfast [was] the biggest shipyard in the world” at the turn of the 20th century.

The city also had the biggest ropeworks in the world. A thousand ancillary metal workshops and foundries banged and clanged away night and day across the city. Engineering firms … clattered non-stop to build and export machinery for factories all over the British Empire.
Against this backdrop, the socialistic and protectionist language of nationalist “economists” must have appeared as pure insanity to northern unionists.

Economic issues cannot be discounted for their importance in understanding unionist opposition to an Irish government. At the same time, other issues driving Protestant fears would prove even more divisive.

Under Sinn Fein’s proposal for dual monarchy, Britain and Ireland would remain wed in a “United Kingdom” under the British monarch, but governed by separate parliaments, effectively placing government of the island in the hands of its Irish Catholic majority. Catholicism, not Protestantism, would be the state religion. Protestants foresaw in this an end to Protestantism in Ireland. Adding fuel to this fire was the Ne Temere decree in 1908 which required that the children of “mixed marriages” be brought up as Catholics, a proposal the Vatican wanted enforced through pre-nuptial agreements. This helps explain the anti -Irish slogan of the time, “Home Rule is Rome Rule!”

Another area of grave concern to unionists was their “Britishness.” Culture in British -controlled Ireland was essentially anglicized. The Irish language and other vestiges of Gaelic ethnicity were virtually nonexistent under British rule. To counter this, the separatist movement emphasized rejuvenation of Irish culture. Irish nationalists wanted to create an Irish Volksgeist, a wave of popular opinion which would embrace “Irishness” in all its forms. Feeney writes,

By the end of the nineteenth century, [Irish separatists] demanded not only political independence, they sought to emphasise and develop Ireland’s distinctiveness or separateness from England in all respects — in sport, language, literature, culture and history.… Advanced nationalists wanted Ireland to be unapologetically, recognizably, even aggressively Irish, and to this end set about purging English influences from the country. [Emphasis added.]

Scott McPherson is a policy advisor at The Future of Freedom Foundation.

1 Comments:

Blogger R7 said...

Government Interventionism in Ireland, Part 2

by Scott McPherson, September 8, 2004

In 1881, the Young Ireland Society was formed. The Gaelic Athletic Association and the Gaelic League followed soon after. The Gaelic League began selling Irish-language textbooks and by 1906 had 900 branches boasting 100,000 members in urban areas around the country. The same Arthur Griffith who would found Sinn Fein in 1905 had in 1900 created an organization called Cumann na nGaedheal (“Irish Council”), which hoped to advance Irish nationalism through, among other things, “the study and teaching of Irish history, literature, language, music and art,” “the discountenancing of anything tending towards the Anglicisation of Ireland,” and, perhaps most important, “the physical and intellectual training of the young.”

Ulster Protestants saw the writing on the wall. Under an Irish government, all power would be vested in a centralized socialistic government while an alien culture controlled their economy, sport, literature, religion, language, and, worst of all, education — the “intellectual training” of their young — with an eye towards the eradication of “anything tending towards the Anglicisation of Ireland.” As Feeney writes in Sinn Fein: A Hundred Turbulent Years, “Unionists were staring at a gigantic Gaelic, Catholic, republican juggernaut.... Certainly there seemed to be no role for them in the sort of Ireland” envisaged by nationalists.

The desire to use a strong government to enforce this cultural revolution remains unchanged to this day. Gerry Adams, president of Sinn Fein since 1983, wrote in Free Ireland (1986) that nationalists had to lead a “reconquest of Ireland by the Irish people, which means the expulsion of imperialism in all its forms, political, economic, military, social and cultural.”

It means the establishment of a real Irish republic and the organisation of the economy so that all its resources are under Irish control and organised to bring maximum benefit to our people in a ... state in which Irish culture and national identity are strong and confident.... My understanding of socialism is that it is a definite form of society in which the main means of production, distribution and exchange are socially owned and controlled and in which production is based on human need rather than private profit. Socialism is based on the most thorough-going democratisation of the economic system, side by side with the most thorough-going democratisation in politics and public affairs. [Emphasis added.]
It may have been purely coincidental, but Adams placed his chapter “Republicanism and Socialism,” from which the preceding quotations were taken, back to back with the chapter entitled “Culture.” “The struggle against cultural colonialism must be a key part of the reconquest of Ireland, of the making of a new Irish humanity,” he wrote.

My own conviction is that the restoration of our culture must be a crucial part of our political struggle and that the restoration of the Irish language must be a central part of the cultural struggle.
The 1798 United Irishman’s rebellion had been initiated with the intention of forming a

brotherhood of affection, a communion of rites and union of power among Irishmen of every religious persuasion, and thereby to obtain a complete reform of the legislature founded on principles of political and religious liberty. [Emphasis added.]
Somehow, between the euphoria of 18th-century liberal thinking and the constitutional crisis of 1914, the wish for Irish separation from Great Britain had mutated from a liberal quest for self-determination into a tool of socialist authoritarians bent on using an Irish state to impose an economic, social, and cultural regime on all of its inhabitants. At the least, that was the very real fear of several hundred thousand Ulster Protestants who were not at all interested in having everything Irish forced down their throats.

Then, as now, the Irish separatist movement pointed to America’s own fight for independence from Great Britain to gain sympathy for their cause around the world and particularly in the United States. They hoped to claim an affinity with the revolutionaries of 1776 to bolster support for an Irish revolution in the early 1900s. To their detriment, they failed to see that a yearning to be free of English rule is where any similarities between the two movements ended.


The American experiment

During 1775–1787, Americans were experimenting with the idea of government as a tool for protecting individual rights, not a means for controlling the economy or promoting a particular language, culture, religion, or form of education. As a matter of fact, Americans created a central government that was largely restricted from interfering in any of those areas — precisely to avoid the kind of conflict that has raged in Ireland. The extent to which the U.S. government has been held within those constitutional bounds explains how America’s many cultures have generally co-existed quite peacefully, by comparison, for most of its history.

The trouble is, Irish separatism at that time fell victim to the trends of the age. Government interventionism, of one form or another, was the dominant creed in the early 20th century, and Ireland’s intellectuals, like so many others around the world, succumbed to the belief in salvation through government control. Unfortunately, it is precisely the craving for government control that made their hopes for self-determination so unappealing to a significant minority of their population, the very people whose cooperation they required to make a peaceful departure from British control.

It was around this same time that an early libertarian commentator would accurately capture the spirit of the times and prescribe the appropriate antidote. In 1927, Ludwig von Mises’s Liberalism: The Classical Tradition addressed the very problems that were only exacerbated by Irish nationalists’ interventionist tendencies. “One can assume that the desire for peace is today universal,” he wrote. “But the peoples of the world are not at all clear as to what conditions would have to be fulfilled in order to secure peace.” Nowhere was this truer than in early 20th-century Ireland.

According to Mises,

The first requirement [for peace] is private property. When private property must be respected [and] private ownership of the means of production prevails everywhere, an important motive for [conflict] has already been excluded.
This was completely contrary to the views of Ireland’s socialists, who wanted to expropriate the private property of Protestant industrialists in their class war, or, at the very least, indirectly commandeer a large percentage of their earnings by curtailing their ability to trade in world markets.

“However,” Mises continues,

this is far from being enough to guarantee peace. So that the exercise of the right of self-determination may not be reduced to a farce, political institutions must be such as to render the transference of sovereignty over a territory from one government to another a matter of the least possible significance, involving no advantage or disadvantage to anyone.” [Emphasis added.]
In order for peace to reign in an Ireland of two divided cultures, the minority had to believe firmly that Walter Long’s fears of “the loss of individual liberty, the absolute insecurity of property” were unfounded. The economic designs of Arthur Griffith and James Connolly would have done nothing to advance such a belief. “Every interference on the part of the government in economic life can become a means of persecuting [minorities],” Mises warned.


Education, religion, and the state

Education and culture likewise had to be removed from the political sphere to ensure stability and peace. “The right of self-determination works to the advantage only of those who comprise the majority,” Mises advises. If Catholics and Protestants are to live peacefully side by side, neither must have the ability to impose a foreign culture on the other. The best means of having that ability, of course, would be government control of the educational system. “Whoever controls the schools has the power to injure other nationalities and to benefit his own,” Mises wrote. Consequently,

the state, the government, the laws must not in any way concern themselves with schooling or education. Public funds must not be used for such purposes. The rearing and instruction of youth must be left entirely to parents and to private associations and institutions.
No self-respecting socialist, however, would ever consider for a moment separating education from the machinations of the state.

Religion, too, would have to be removed from the prerogatives of political planners. It has been suggested that the religious differences of the Catholic and Protestant populations of Ireland would always be an insurmountable barrier to any measure of peaceful coexistence. Here again the example of the United States contradicts such a view. In the United States, religions of every kind are practiced with no organized sectarian conflict. This is so exactly because the First Amendment forbids government from favoring one religion over another.

Admittedly, even under a government strictly confined in its powers to preserving the life, liberty, and property of the individual citizens under its care, tensions would continue to exist between conflicting nationalities. But as Mises concludes, such tensions “become quite intolerable in an interventionist or socialist state.”

If the administrative authorities have the right to intervene everywhere according to their free discretion, if the latitude granted to judges and officials in reaching their decisions is so wide as to leave room also for the operation of political prejudices, then a member of a national minority finds himself delivered over to arbitrary judgment and oppression on the part of the public functionaries belonging to the ruling majority.
In a description that applies fittingly to later developments in Ireland, Mises predicts that in such a state “hatred ... must become ever fiercer and continue to ignite new ... rebellions.” Just as in so many other nations, the principles of a libertarian society would have best provided the necessary conditions for peaceful coexistence between members of the two ethnic, religious, and national groups in Ireland.

To be sure, the Protestant leadership certainly played its own part in Ireland’s political troubles. Nationalist political and labor leaders were brutally suppressed and imprisoned, Irish lands were unfairly confiscated, and pogroms were initiated against Catholic neighborhoods in Belfast, giving socialists the ammunition they needed to paint words like “capitalism” and “liberty” as synonymous with oppressive, discriminatory government. The seeds of pressure-group warfare were sown. Catholics wrongly — but understandably — drew the conclusion that in order to be politically free, they would need government’s reins, driving them into the ranks of the socialists.


Political liberty and economic liberty

It could be argued that no conciliatory measures would have brought the Protestant minority in Ulster around to the idea of a united Ireland. This is probably correct — in the short term. Had Irish nationalists espoused a philosophy of true political freedom — free markets, individual rights and private property, and limited government — rather than one of government interventionism, statism, and political control, there is every reason to believe that the majority of unionists would at least have been less suspicious of their Catholic neighbors and more prepared to see the Home Rule Act as no threat to their British values. That would have gone a long way towards tempering hotheads in the nationalist community and maybe even preventing the turmoil and violence that would mark Irish politics for decades thereafter. As it was, republicans would not seriously consider the possibility of decentralized government in Ireland until the 1970s.

It is interesting to note that the British government itself throughout the 20th century would become more and more enamored of economic interventionism and the socialistic welfare state. If Irish nationalists had from the start embraced libertarianism instead of socialism, forging a link with the Protestant community on the basis of shared affection for the principles of a free society, the two groups could well have fashioned a political alliance against greater centralization of power in London in later years. In time, Ireland might have become united in the minds of its entire people against British socialists, resolved to oppose any encroachment on the liberties of Irish citizens — Catholic and Protestant alike.

11:58 AM  

Post a Comment

<< Home